Tax informality in LAC: are we still fishing inside the fish tank?
Tax informality is part of the so-called hidden, informal, submerged, underground, black economy, etc., which is defined as all the legal production of goods and services oriented to the market that are deliberately removed from government control (Schneider 2010), both to avoid the tax burden and Social Security contributions, as well as government regulations and records.
Depending on the approach, it may be motivated by an individual rational decision or be the result of an exclusion from the system. From the decision point of view, there are two essential factors as a cause of this phenomenon:
It could be said that an acceptable level of tax burden and a simplification of formal obligations would lead to formalization. But they would be insufficient to solve this problem.
There are countries with the same tax burden and formal obligations, but with different levels of compliance, where the effectiveness of the TA’s control plays a preponderant role, together with the level of governance or institutional practice ( political acceptance of government decisions), social behaviors (fiscal compliance of the taxpayer environment) and their civic or ethical level (tax awareness or moral conscience).
On the other hand, it has been pointed out that other keys are in the application of effective sanctions, but they would also be incomplete if the perception of benefit is not incorporated. That is, to motivate the individual rational decision that more benefits are obtained by being within the system than being kept out of it.
The universe of taxpayers can be classified according to their connection with the TS, namely:
Informality implies non – compliance with the TS and its TA. It is the most serious of the tax behavior, but paradoxically it is one that generates little government action to find a solution.
Tax policy makers in Lac have been characterized by establishing strategies with varying success in relation to the special regimes and the general regime[1], but have not taken into account the informal sector, a strategy that popular wisdom has defined as “hunting inside the zoo “or “fishing inside the fish tank”.
Beyond great proclamations, very little has been done in practice, and this is demonstrated by the fact that action in most cases has been limited to passively waiting for the expansive economic cycle to incorporate them. Experience shows that this is not enough, since the incorporation of taxpayers is very slow during economic expansion, [2]but very sharp in recession.[3] This pessimistic view implies that nothing can be done in the matter, omitting to generate active state policies.
Another common mistake in analyzing this segment is to consider that it only includes people in the subsistence economy. A fact little considered is that these small taxpayers are supplied by wholesalers and larger industries, which form chains of informality[4] and the service sector has tax significance. Another aggravating factor is that on this black market, the commercialization of smuggled or illegally acquired items proliferates, which also encourages criminal activity.
Tax informality can in turn be classified into a) total, and b) partial. In the first, the taxpayer is not registered, while in the second, he is registered in one or some taxes but not all.
From the above, the following conclusions are drawn:
[1] Except El Salvador and Venezuela.
[2] Gómez Sabaíni, Morán (2012), La Informalidad y Tributación en América Latina…”, CEPAL, AECID. Santiago.
[3] Barcena (2020) argued that in LAC there is a 54% of labor informality, and by the end of 2020 a decline in GDP of – 9.1% is expected, and there will be a 15-year decline in poverty (231 million people) and a 30-year decline in extreme poverty (96 million people) @eclal_onu.[4] Ana de la Herrán Piñar (2020), “La economía sumergida infectada por el coronavirus”, ABC, Madrid.
[5] Catalan Gascon (2020), closing speech of the Master of Public Finance and tax and Financial Administration, UNED, IEF, AEAT, Madrid.
[6] In addition to tax registers and other electronic devices for recording and issuing tax invoices and vouchers.
[7] Successful strategy implemented by Carlos Miguel Tacchi in the Public Revenue Secretariat of Argentina in the 1990s.
[8] Today only three countries apply it: Argentina, Colombia, and Uruguay.
1,571 total views, 1 views today